Digital Cooperatives may become the default corporate structure in the Blockchain Economy

Digital Coops.001.jpeg

Governance matters and Blockchain changes the rules on governance. Some people were drawn to Bitcoin and Blockchain because they sensed that the current system was broken and they hoped that what Satoshi Nakamoto released in the dark days of the Global Financial Crisis would help fix it.Since then we have had nearly a decade of money printing and debt creation. Has that fixed the problem that we all saw so visibly during the Global Financial Crisis or has it simply made the next crisis worse? Could Blockchain enable a fundamentally more equitable society without losing entrepreneurial dynamism?

This is Part 1/Chapter 7 in The Blockchain Economy book. This serialised book is a practical guidebook for investors, entrepreneurs and employees who want to learn how to prosper during the transition to an economy where value exchange is permissionless and disintermediated. For the index please go here.

The media has focussed on the surging bitcoin price and images of conspicuous consumption and the subsequent price crash and doom/gloom stories. All this price fixation overwhelmed all those early thoughts of fixing the system. We replaced “get rich quick by buying and flipping property” in the subprime era with “get rich quick by buying and flipping bitcoin”.

This Chapter covers:

  • Historical Perspective – There Is No Alternative (TINA)

 

  • Introducing Digital Cooperatives

 

  • In the Analog era, happy workers did not matter and  customers only cared about price

 

  • Customer Cooperatives in the digital economy

 

  • Worker Cooperative experiments that failed

 

  • Digital Worker Cooperatives for the Gig Economy

 

  • Networks owned by the users

 

  • Yes but KISS, Blockchain please

 

  • Tezos for Irony Aficionados

 

  • The Wolf of Wall Street on LSD

 

  • Both bleeding edge modern and really old fashioned

 

Historical Perspective – There Is No Alternative (TINA)

Capitalism may be in crisis, but the alternative (communism) is worse, so Queen TINA rules.

When Capitalism lost it’s natural enemy, after the collapse of the Soviet Union, Capitalism started a long move towards the crisis that hit us in 2008. This crisis of Capitalism is a problem because the alternative of Communism is clearly a failed system/ideology.

During the Cold War, the West had to convince people in both the developed and developing world that capitalism was better for the people by spreading wealth broadly. After the Berlin Wall collapsed, when the people no longer needed to be convinced because there was no competing ideology, wealth went to a smaller and smaller group of people through the process of Financialization. Without a stake in the capitalist system, people moved to populism of both the left and the right and this came to a head in 2016 with Brexit and then the resurgence of the left wing of the Labor Party in the UK and the election of Donald Trump in America. Populism of left and right could destroy capitalism, which will be a disaster because the alternative (communism) has already been proven to fail.

Introducing Digital Cooperatives

The best hope for a revised and sustainable version of Capitalism comes from the concept of digital cooperatives where workers, customers and owners are aligned. The Security Token model is ideally suited as the funding and governance mechanism for Digital Cooperatives.

This post explore three types of Digital Cooperatives;

  • Customer Cooperatives

 

  • Worker Cooperatives

 

  • Hybrid Customer + Worker Cooperatives.

Successful governance models need to look after both customers and workers, so the hybrid model is likely to win. Shareholder primacy has been the mantra of the Financialization Economy, sometimes at the expense of either customers or workers or both. This will change during the Blockchain Economy when ownership will be shared more equally among customers and workers, benefiting the few passive investors along for the ride.

When customers and workers are shareholders you only have two interests to look after, making governance a lot easier.

Shareholder returns are then a byproduct of happy customers and happy workers. If either customers or workers become unhappy, eventually shareholders lose.

In the Analog era, happy workers did not matter and  customers only cared about price

If you are in the extraction business – getting something like oil or gold or other commodities out of the earth – you don’t need to worry at all about how happy your workers or customers are. Customers only care about price/quality and your price can be low if you pay low wages to workers (who are fungible and easily replaced and have little impact on the quality of the product).

That became slightly less true in the manufacturing economy. Henry Ford famously wanted workers paid enough so that they could afford his cars. Sadly in most cases it is a tragedy of the commons. Companies want somebody else to ensure that people have enough money to buy their products, so manufacturing workers are unhappy and, apart from a few people, customers don’t care enough to vote with their wallet against companies that treat workers badly.

In the services and knowledge economy, the happiness of the worker matters.

For example, if you engage a consultant or investment banker on a critical job, it matters if that person thinks their job sucks and they don’t like their employer. The knowledge economy is really the knowledge workers economy.

The same is true if you walk into a coffee shop or any other services operation where your experience matters to you. Miserable workers, grinning inanely because the company policy tells them they will be fired if they do not act happy, does not make for a good experience.

The services economy is really the “experience economy”.

Digitisation enables new experiences at low prices. The Digital Economy intersects with the knowledge and services economy but have not connected properly due to a governance mismatch. That governance mismatch can be fixed in the Blockchain Economy.

There is a critical and privileged role for the seed investor in the Blockchain Economy. Do you want to be invested in the past – the extraction and manufacturing economy – or the future of the knowledge and services economy? Investors will need to change their attitude to risk by investing earlier based on fundamental analysis.

The idea of Cooperatives is not new. Before looking into the future of Digital Cooperatives, we will look at some successful and not so successful Cooperative models from the past.

Customer Cooperatives in the digital economy

There are plenty of other Customer Cooperatives – think of community banks or Coop Grocery stores for example.

One example of a Customer Cooperative where the ownership structure fundamentally change the game is Vanguard. The customer in this case is a shareholder of the funds; there are no outside investors. This structure allows Vanguard to win by charging very low fees (see this post for more). This Customer Cooperative structure makes Vanguard the real disrupter in the Wealthtech segment of Fintech. When they started in 1975, their average expense ratio was 0.89%. By 2014 this had dropped to 0.18%. Given their scale, network effects and customer ownership structure, nobody can undercut Vanguard on price and in a commodity market such as passive index funds, price is the deciding factor. Vanguard’s growth numbers tell the story:

  • 32 years to reach $1 trillion in assets.

 

  • 8 years to get to $2 trillion.

 

  • 3 years to get to $3 trillion.

Another example is SWIFT. There are two stories around SWIFT:

  • 1970s era technology that will get obliterated by new Blockchain based technology.

 

  • An ownership structure that means that the customers aka shareholders are more likely to trust SWIFT to deliver that new Blockchain based technology than any other firm.

The Vanguard and SWIFT stories tells us that ownership matters in the real world of advanced knowledge based firms. These are not organic farming hippy cooperatives.

Worker Cooperative experiments that failed. 

The early Worker Cooperatives that grew out of socialist movements in the 1970s mostly failed due to a simple alignment of interest issue. As a young man, I loved old British motorbikes, so I hoped that a worker cooperative model would save Triumph from Japanese competition. It did not. If employees are owners it is too simple to get employees to vote for a pay increase that will make the business unprofitable; it is a tragedy of the commons. The resurgence of left wing populism is bringing back these ideas, but they are likely to fail for the same reasons.

Digital Worker Cooperatives for the Gig Economy

If the workers are free agents, these micro-entrepreneurs will be much more thoughtful about when and how to raise prices than a salaried employee might.

This is starting to happen in some sectors of the economy. Daily Fintech profiled one example (a Dentist Cooperative). The idea is simply that the ownership of these gig economy networks remains primarily with those who provide the services in those networks. If it works for dentists, why not doctors, drivers….well you name it.

Networks owned by the users

Imagine if Mark Zuckerberg’s next door neighbour at Harvard had the same simple but brilliant idea for a social network and built a good enough product (pretty simple), but decided to offer the first few thousand users a big % of the equity. He or she would be very wealthy (albeit not as wealthy as Mark Zuckerberg) and few thousand people who made it happen would have had their lives changed. Their ownership stake might have given them more incentive to make the network successful rather than a competing network owned by one individual and few investors in Silicon Valley.

In the case of social networks, the User is also the Producer; they produce for free in return for getting a free service. They are also the Product being sold to advertisers. So a User Cooperative is slightly different from a Worker or Customer Cooperative.

Yes But KISS, Blockchain Please

In theory all that sounds good enough, but the Eeyore response to all that Tigger excitement is “the admin issues of thousands of people who combine a role as customers, workers and users makes this an impossible pipe dream”.

That is why we have Smart Contracts and Distributed Autonomous Organisations (DAO). The admin/back office issues are manageable thanks to Blockchain.

A well designed ICO enables a Digital Cooperative. The Ethereum ICO in 2014 is a good example. The early Ethereum investors were also the  early workers and the early customers. They understood enough about the technical risk to evaluate that and by building the DAPPS they got to Product Market Fit. Through this simple alignment of interest, Ethereum overcame both technical and market risk.

Tezos for Irony Aficionados

A startup aiming to solve the governance issues around cybercurrencies collapsing into law suits and bankruptcies is pretty delicious for irony aficionados. I never quite understood how Tezos was going to fix the governance issues but clearly they did not eat their own dog food.

The Wolf of Wall Street on LSD

Wall Street is pretty shameless, but the long hot summer of ICO in 2017 showed us what a totally unregulated alternative looks like and it may be worse. This is a million miles away from what inspired techies and idealists to get involved with a deeply nerdy White Paper from an unknown individual on an obscure cryptography site in 2009 and also what got people to put their money and time behind the wild dreams of a decentralised computer from a 19 year old programmer called Vitalik Buterin.

The Critical and Privileged Role of the Seed Investor

Traditional analog and manufacturing businesses are cash capital intensive but low on intellectual capital intensity. Digital businesses are much more cash capital efficient but totally reliant on intellectual capital. You need less cash capital, but you do need some. There is still role for the early investors. If you get in early on a capital efficient business that gets to Product Market Fit, you are golden. The ICO innovation, for all its sketchy characters and craziness, is democratising early stage investing.

During the founding days of VC it had very little to do with fund management and everything to do with innovation. As the VC industry grew to become a huge part of our economy, many VC Funds became more about fund management than innovation. All the incentive in fund management is to grow fund size. That naturally pushes you away from seed investing. Lets say you want a $100m fund (giving you $2m to run the business based on 2% AUM fee). Picking 100 deals at $1m each at Seed stage is too much hard work. You much prefer to do 10 deals at $10m each – and investing $10m at Seed stage is not wise.

When VC industry deserted the seed stage, they opened up a window for Blockchain Finance.

Into that market gap – huge demand at Seed stage not being met by supply – came the ICO innovation in all its messy, sketchy, semi-legal glory. A well-designed ICO that reduces both technical risk and market risk, because those who can evaluate technical risk and market risk buy the Tokens, is a game-changer for investors, workers and customers. Message to regulators – don’t throw out the baby (game-changing innovation) with the bathwater (scammy ICO promoters). Smart regulation that is tech driven, not just using lots of lawyers and paper, can be a win for both entrepreneurs and investors.

Both bleeding edge modern and really old fashioned

Digital Cooperatives are both bleeding edge modern and really old fashioned

  • bleeding edge modern. Digital Cooperatives  need Security Tokens.

 

  • really old fashioned.  Digital Cooperatives  cannot exit via trade sale. Members buy into a governance model and that governance model could be changed by the acquirer. So the financial return can only be via really old fashioned Dividends (you know, how Warren Buffet thinks).

Bernard Lunn is a Fintech deal-maker, author, adviser and thought-leader.

You can reach out directly to discuss our advisory services by sending an email to julia at dailyfintech dot com

Get fresh daily insights from an amazing team of Fintech thought leaders around the world. Ride the Fintech wave by reading us daily in your email.

8 comments

  1. Your argument went from plausible to laudable in mere paragraphs, sketching a bigger picture than most see. The landscape is more layered than most people realize, especially policymakers. We have a catch-22 here: Many countries have policymakers who are under-qualified… how many governments and institutions need to be educated? Can an ICO fix that? Then… there is the issue of verification of work done, in many industries, to prevent a system being gamed, where the watchers are in on it… IoT is not ready to fix this… yet.

  2. Suppose you have a user-ownership model for a social network running on a blockchain protocol. Its potential market value will only ever be a fraction of Facebook’s, since it cannot extract the same monopoly rents. Public blockchains use open-source protocol software and what’s to stop anyone from forking the existing social network and offering an identical product but with lower costs to users? And on and on until you reach zero rents.

    The absence of property rights means that your hypothetical first 1000 users of Zuck’s next-door neighbour will never become wealthy.

    • True. To get mega wealth, follow the Zuck model. My post was about how many people can earn life-changing amounts of money. One Zuck and 7 billion consumers seems a less interesting story – unless you happen to be Zuck of course.

  3. In my model, those early users do have property rights. It is still capitalism but just with more broad distribution

    • But how would such property rights be designed and enforced in an open-source blockchain protocol economy?

      What most crypto-bulls fail to see is that any network business that runs on a blockchain will lead to huge destruction of economic value for investors.

      Do you see any way to mitigate this without resorting to a closed blockchain, which quite defeats the purpose of having a blockchain-based network business in the first place.

      • I am not sure I see the problem. I am not being argumentative, just don’t see the issue. Maybe I am making an assumption that I did not spell out. If a token is a Security Token it can entitle the holder to beneficial interest such as dividends. Some platforms and jurisdictions emerging that will enable Security Tokens – we are not there yet, but direction of travel is clear.

  4. Thanks for your response. Perhaps I failed to articulate the problem well. Let me have another go.

    For a ‘traditional’ network business like Facebook, even if all of Zuck’s senior developers decided to leave and start their own rival service, the odds are stacked against their success because of network effects (it is too much trouble for existing Facebook to migrate to a new platform). The costs of ‘forking’ are simply too high.

    In an open-source blockchain protocol economy, the costs of forking an existing protocol are many orders of magnitude lower. This limits the economic rent enjoyed by the network business, which means that the enterprise value such a business running on a blockchain protocol will pale in comparison to its non-blockchain equivalent.

    The logical conclusion of all this is that a shift to a open-source blockchain protocol economy will be great for users, but bad for investors/owners. I’d be glad to have your view on this.

  5. “If employees are owners it is too simple to get employees to vote for a pay increase that will make the business unprofitable; it is a tragedy of the commons.”

    Worker cooperatives, according to research, are *more* likely to cut wages rather than lay-off people. This idea that they would raise their wages too much might be intuitive but there is no research indicating it, indeed the research shows the opposite. This is because workers in these firms are more likely to believe that the wage cuts are reversed later on than workers in conventional firms. This leads to a counterintuitive finding that worker cooperatives actually pay slightly lower average wages than otherwise similar conventional firms! It’s basically a trade-off – worker coops provide stable employment and volatile wages, investor owned companies provide volatile employment and stable wages.

    See “Employer moral hazard and wage rigidity. The case of worker owned and investor owned firms” by Albanese et al. (2017) for example.

    The problems with worker cooperatives have to do with lack of incentives to start one, once they are up and running they have higher productivity and lower risk of bankruptcy.

    Nevertheless, interesting article!

Leave a Reply

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.